|
The Myth of the
Money Multiplier
|
The textbook money multiplier
asserts
that the lending of banks automatically expands the credit money supply
to a multiple of their aggregate reserves. In its basic form,
that
multiple is equal to the reciprocal of the required reserve
ratio.
In the U.S. the required ratio is currently 10%, which implies the
money
supply should be about ten times larger than the aggregate reserves of
banks. Then what are we to make of the money multiplier concept
in
a country like Canada where the reserve requirement is zero?
The Myth
The money multiplier
concept implicitly assumes that the Fed
controls the money
supply by setting the required reserve ratio, and then issuing enough
reserves to enable aggregate bank lending to a multiple of that
ratio. Since demand deposits in U.S.
banks
remain at roughly the expected multiple of reserves, that would seem to
confirm the money multiplier thesis. It is then easy to conclude
that the causal relation runs from reserves to loans, and thus to
deposits. In truth, it runs in exactly the
opposite direction.
The money multiplier concept represents a misunderstanding about how the credit money supply grows. Banks
with
adequate capital can and do lend without adequate reserves on
hand.
If a bank has a creditworthy borrower and a profitable lending opportunity, it
will issue the loan and then if necessary borrow reserves in the money
market to meet the reserve ratio requirement.
Managing Aggregate
Reserves
A bank's reserves are counted as the average held during
successive
14-day periods. That averaging allows a bank to run below its
required
level on any given day and thereby provides flexibility in meeting the
reserve requirements. Most large banks are deposit poor and must
borrow the required reserves in the money market. Smaller banks
are
generally deposit rich and often lend their excess reserves to larger
banks.
As a bank increases its lending, that increases its
demand deposits so it must increase
its holding of
reserves. If there is a shortage of aggregate reserves in the
banking
system, only the Fed can make up the difference. As long as the
Fed's
policy is to control the Fed funds rate, it must supply whatever
reserves
are required to meet the demand. Conversely as aggregate bank
lending
decreases, the Fed must drain reserves. Total reserves are thus a
dependent variable, not a control variable as implied in the money
multiplier concept.
The Uses of Excess
Reserves
A bank gains reserves when someone deposits cash or a
check written
on another bank. The deposit increases the bank's assets and
liabilities
equally, thus leaving its capital unchanged. Whether the new
deposit
increases the bank's lending power depends on its capital adequacy,
i.e.
the ratio of its capital to its risk-weighted assets. A new
deposit
does not affect the bank's capital ratio since reserves are
risk-free.
However new loans by the bank would add to its risk-weighted assets and
thus reduce its capital ratio. If the bank were loaned up to its
capital ratio limit, the additional reserves would not increase its
lending
power.
Banks are seldom loaned up to the capital adequacy
constraint.
In that case whether the added reserves will be used to support
additional
lending depends on the opportunities that exist at the time.
Reserves
earn no interest, so banks with excess reserves are likely to lend
them
at interest to other banks in the Fed funds market. If there isn't
sufficient
demand for reserves, the Fed will have to recapture the excess in order
to maintain control of the Fed funds rate. It does that by
selling
T-bills from its own portfolio.
The next article presents a case history that exposes
another textbook
myth, namely that varying the reserve ratio requirement is a way of
controlling
the credit money supply.
Next
Article Home
|