Full Reserve Banking by William F Hummel updated July 4, 2016 A near melt-down of the financial system in 2008 has sparked
a renewed interest in full reserve banking. Some believe that fractional
reserve banking is a root cause of asset price bubbles that can end in debt
deflation and deep recessions. In the following, we outline a full reserve
system for the U.S. and compare it with the current fractional reserve system
for individual banks and for the banking system as a whole. Individual Bank
Operations In full reserve banking, every bank would be required to hold
reserves equal at all times to its transaction deposits. Those reserves
are effectively bound to the deposits and therefore could not be used by the
bank. We will call them bound reserves. For its
own investments -- making loans or buying securities -- a bank would need
additional reserves. We will call them free reserves. As in
fractional reserve banking, reserves could be held in any combination of vault
cash and deposits at the Fed. They would not be required against savings or
term deposits, but all deposits would be insured by the FDIC up to specified
dollar limits. In fractional reserve banking, the distinction between free
reserves and bound reserves is less relevant. As long as the bank can meet the
reserve ratio requirement on average over a 14-day period, it
can use all of its reserves to cover a new loan. This
provides a degree of freedom not available in full reserve banking. Regardless of the required reserve ratio, a bank must have
sufficient reserves to cover a loan on the day it is made. If the bank is in
good standing and temporarily short of reserves, it may receive a daylight
advance from the Fed. However the amount of the advance is limited to a
fraction of the bank's capital, and is subject to an interest charge. A bank acquires new reserves whenever it receives a new
transaction deposit. However in full reserve banking, all those reserves would
be bound rather than free. To increase its lending power, the bank would need
to acquire additional free reserves. Its options are: (1) borrow from the Fed,
(2) borrow from another bank, (3) borrow from a non-bank, (4) induce its
transaction account holders to move funds into savings or term deposits, (5)
sell assets in the open market, or (6) sell additional bank shares to investors. Option 1 is normally used to address liquidity issues rather
than as a source of funds to lend because Fed loans are designed to cost more
than other options. Option 2 simply transfers free reserves between the
banks without increasing the total. All other options increase free reserves
but at the expense of reducing aggregate transaction deposits. Then how
could the transaction money supply grow in a full reserve system? The answer
is: through open market operations by the Fed. Accounting Details Each bank would need two accounts at the Fed, a Bound Reserves
Account (BRA) and a Free Reserves Account (FRA). The BRA together with the
bank's vault cash should equal its total transaction deposit liabilities. The
FRA would hold the bank’s discretionary funds. Each bank would report its total transaction deposits and its
vault cash to the Fed at daily closing. The difference should equal what it
holds in its BRA. If there is a discrepancy, the Fed would transfer funds
between the bank’s BRA and FRA as needed to correct it. When a bank makes a loan, it would transfer that amount from its
FRA to its BRA. Conversely when the loan is paid off, it would transfer that
amount from the bank's BRA to its FRA. When the bank makes payment for an
investment or for goods and services, the Fed would debit the bank’s FRA and
credit the BRA of the recipient’s bank. When a bank depositor deposits a check in his account, the bank
would credit his transaction account with that amount and report the payment to
the Fed. The Fed would debit the payer bank’s BRA and credit he payee bank’s BRA.
It would then instruct the payer’s bank to reduce the balance in the payer’s
transaction account. When a depositor moves funds from his transaction account to a
term or savings account, it would free up that much of the bank’s bound
reserves. This would be noted in the bank’s daily report to the Fed, who would
transfer funds from the bank’s BRA to its FRA. Conversely if a depositor
allowed a loan to the bank to mature or moved funds from his savings account to
his transaction account, it would be reported to the Fed who would transfer
funds from the bank’s FRA to its BRA. If a bank depositor withdraws or deposits cash, the difference
between total deposits and cash would remain unchanged, thus requiring no
change in the bank's BRA or FRA. Implementing Monetary Policy The Fed would implement monetary policy by setting a target for
the interest rate on interbank loans of free reserves. It would offer to lend free
reserves to banks with adequate collateral at 40 basis points above the target
rate and borrow at 40 basis points below the target rate. These margins could
be adjusted by the Fed to control the total amount of such lending and
borrowing. By observing the amount loaned versus the amount borrowed in a
given period, the Fed could determine the amount of reserves it needs to add or
drain to balance supply versus demand at the target rate. The Fed would buy or sell securities in the open market thus adding
or draining transaction deposits and their related reserves. However open
market operations (OMO) with the non-bank sector can only create bound reserves
equal to the increase in transaction deposits. The excess of funds in
non-interest-earning transaction deposits would induce the sellers to move some
of their funds into term deposits at the same bank. Any such purchases would
convert that much in bound reserves to free reserves, and thereby influence the
interest rate on interbank loans. In the fractional reserve system, the Fed controls the short-term
interest rate by operating on a relatively small pool of reserves. That
pool would be considerably larger in a full reserve system since it would
comprise the discretionary funds (free reserves) of the entire banking system.
Therefore in a full reserve system the Fed would have to deal in larger
increments in open market operations to achieve the same level of control. The Banking System From the perspective of non-bank firms and households, the banking
system in a full reserve regime would not seem much different from the current
fractional reserve system. However banks would have to work harder to make the
same kinds of profits, and that could affect the fees charged for their
depository services. Since new transaction deposits would bring no free
reserves to a bank, banks would have little incentive to seek them unless they
believed the depositors would move some of the funds into savings or term
deposits. To enhance the stability of the banking system, new operating
rules and restrictions for banks should be established. For example a bank's capital
(assets minus liabilities) should be at least 10% of its risk-weighted assets.
A bank should be required to hold on its own balance sheet at least 10% of each
loan it issues so as to share in the risk of a default by the borrower. Permissible
investments should exclude those whose basic purpose is to leverage bets in the
financial markets. Money Supply Growth Government spending has no net effect on
aggregate bank reserves and transaction deposits in either a full reserve or
fractional reserve system. The Treasury spends out of its account at the Fed
which it must continually replenish to avoid depletion. It does so with
transfers from its commercial bank accounts where it deposits receipts from
taxes and the sale of securities. By targeting a fixed balance in its Fed
account, the Treasury leaves total reserves in the banking system unchanged
except for short-term transients. By balancing its inflows against
outflows through the net sale or redemption of securities, the Treasury leaves
the money supply unchanged on average. In effect, the Treasury pays
for its deficit spending with securities rather than money. Since the demand for
loans varies with the interest rate, the total amount of transaction deposits
would depend on the interest rate banks charge on loans, which they would
normally set at a markup from the Fed’s target rate. Thus growth in the money
supply would be endogenous, varying with demand as influenced by the Fed's
target rate. Transition to a Full
Reserve System As of June 2016, reserves totaled about $2,250 billion and transaction deposits
about $1,350 billion, the result of the Fed’s quantitative easing programs. If
the Fed declared the full reserve system in effect at that time, bound reserves
would total about $1,350 billion and free reserves about $900 billion. Banks
would need some portion of those free reserves as working balances, probably
less than $200 billion. The rest would have to be recaptured by the Fed. This
could be done as follows: The Fed would offer securities to banks from its
own portfolio at a discount to induce them to spend their excess free
reserves. It would also declare that bank savings accounts could no longer be
used as checkable deposits. That should induce a movement of some savings
deposits into transaction accounts, thereby converting that much of free
reserves into bound reserves. The interest paid on reserves would be
limited to free reserves only and gradually reduced to zero. Transition to the full reserve system would be complete when total reserves
equaled total bank transaction deposits plus what banks chose to hold in free
reserves after the end of interest on reserves. The interest rate in the
interbank lending market would then be controlled by the Fed through open
market operations as it did before the financial crisis of 2008. |