
|
Deposit
Insurance
and Bank
Failures
|
The following is a digest
of the chapter on "Deposit Insurance" in Financial
Institutions and Markets by Meir
Kohn,
McGraw-Hill, 1994.
A Brief History of Deposit
Insurance
After a rash of
bank failures
in the early 1930s, Federal deposit insurance was enacted by Congress,
but over strong opposition. The opponents argued that it would
encourage
bad banking and eventually become a burden to the taxpayer. But
for
the first time in the history of American banking, there was a lengthy
period without bank runs or banking panics, and very few banks
failed.
That all began to change in the 1970s. It reached a crisis in the
1980s when bank failures, though less numerous, far exceeded the total
assets (in constant dollars) of failed banks in the 1930s.
The S&L
crisis of the 1980s
wiped out the Federal Savings and Loan Insurance Corporation
(FSLIC).
As a result, Congress revised the system. In 1989 deposit
insurance
was consolidated under the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation
(FDIC).
Two funds were set up, the Bank Insurance Fund (BIF) which covers
commercial
banks and savings banks, and the Savings Association Insurance Fund
(SAIF)
which insures deposits at S&Ls. The focus here is on deposit
insurance as it relates to banks.
Insured banks
pay a premium
on all their deposits, even those deposits that are not covered by
insurance.
For many years, premium income exceeded the cost of failures. But
as the size of bank failures increased, the BIF went into the red in
1991.
Instead of being declared insolvent, however, its losses were covered
with
loans from the Treasury, as authorized by Congress. In 1992 the
fund
staged a comeback. With increased premiums and a sharp
improvement
in bank profitability due to a drop in the interest rates, the BIF
repaid
its loans and was well in the black again by mid-1993.
Dealing with Bank Failure
A bank is
insolvent when its
liabilities exceed its assets. The FDIC monitors the banks that it
insures,
but the authority to close a bank rests with whoever gave it a
charter.
Once an insolvent bank is closed, there are three ways for the FDIC to
proceed. They are (1) a payout, (2) a purchase and
assumption,
or (3) a bridge bank. We will examine each of these
options.
Payout
In a payout,
the insolvent
bank is liquidated and ceases to exist. The FDIC pays off its
insured
depositors. It then sells the bank’s assets and uses the proceeds
to pay off the bank’s creditors. These include the owners of
uninsured
deposits and the FDIC itself. The FDIC becomes a creditor by
purchasing
the insured deposits. The creditors share pro rata in whatever
proceeds
are realized from the liquidation.
Purchase
and Assumption
In a purchase
and assumption
(P&A), the FDIC arranges for another bank to purchase the failed
bank
and to assume it liabilities. Banks interested submit bids in an
auction process. There are two versions of P&A. In a clean-bank
P&A, the successful bidder takes over the liabilities but not the
assets.
The FDIC pays the bank the cash value of the liabilities less the
amount
of the bid. It then liquidates the assets and keeps the
proceeds.
In a whole-bank
P&A,
the successful bidder takes over the assets as well as the
liabilities.
The FDIC pays it the value of the liabilities less the market value of
the assets, less the amount of the bid. The net cost to the FDIC
is the same in both versions, but the whole-bank version ties up less
of
its resources because it does not have to take on and liquidate the
loans.
As the amount of the assets the FDIC has under liquidation has soared,
it has increasingly leaned toward the whole-bank version.
Bridge
Bank
In the bridge
bank option,
the FDIC replaces the board of directors of the insolvent bank and
provides
whatever capital is required to reorganize it and get it running
properly.
In exchange, the FDIC receives an equity stake in the bank. While
under the wing of the FDIC, the bank is known as a 'bridge bank' which
continues until a P&A can be arranged or the bank returns to
profitability.
In this version, not only are the liabilities covered, but the original
owners may even come away with something.
FDIC Preferences Regarding Bank
Failure
During most of
its history,
the FDIC has shown a preference for the P&A option. Of the
1813
insured banks that failed between 1934 and 1990, only 552 were
payouts.
Of the 169 banks that failed in 1990, 20 were payouts, 148 were
P&As,
and only one involved a bridge bank.
A payout is
generally the least
expensive for the FDIC because the lost value of the failed bank’s
“franchise”
is usually less than its uninsured liabilities. In a P&A, all
liabilities of the failed bank are covered – both insured and uninsured
deposits as well as non-deposit liabilities such as Fed funds
bought.
Cost however is not the main consideration. If the FDIC believes
that liquidation and its consequent losses to uninsured depositors and
creditors would shake public confidence in the banking system, it may
elect
to bear the greater cost of a P&A.
The Moral Hazard Problem
The purpose
of deposit insurance
is to protect the banking system by eliminating bank runs. If all
deposits
were insured, the likelihood of bank runs would indeed be greatly
reduced.
But that would also increase the moral hazard leading to riskier
banking
practice and outright failures. This dilemma has no easy solution.
Next Article
Home
|